Anyone who has lived through a market correction (the tariff announcements in early April this year being a recent example, though there have been far worse) should be able to see that market prices do not always accurately reflect even the consensus view of value (which itself can be wrong). As people are forced to de-lever, everything goes down at once, often by very similar amounts, even though it cannot be possible that everything suddenly lost the same amount of value simultaneously.
To quote Richard Bookstaber, "The principal reason for intraday price movement is the demand for liquidity... the role of the market is to provide immediacy for liquidity demanders. ...market crises... are the times when liquidity and immediacy matter most. ...the defining characteristic is that time is more important than price. ...diversification strategies fail. Assets that are uncorrelated suddenly become highly correlated, and all positions go down together. The reason for the lack of diversification is that in a high-energy market, all assets in fact are the same.... What matters is who holds the assets." (from A Framework for Understanding Market Crises, 1999)
Was the market drop an accurate reflection of the value that would have been destroyed by those tariffs, discounted by the probability that they would have been enacted as drafted? Nobody knew then, and I maintain that nobody even knows now. That was not the calculation that was being made.
> As people are forced to de-lever, everything goes down at once, often by very similar amounts, even though it cannot be possible that everything suddenly lost the same amount of value simultaneously.
The price of something and the value of something were never expected to be the same. What's the value of food? If you have none you die, so the value is quite high, but the price is much lower than that because there are many competing suppliers.
And the price of a large class like investment securities can easily change all at once if there is a large shift in supply or demand.
Not disagreeing with you, but isn't that already obvious from the fact that economic activity happens in the first place?
If you buy 5 apples from me for $5 then two things must be true: 1. The value that those 5 apples have to you exceeds the value that $5 have to you, at least at this very moment. Otherwise you would hang on to your $5 instead. 2. The value that those 5 apples have to me is less than $5 have to me, otherwise I would hang on to the apples.
The price of those 5 apples at this moment may be $5 but that doesn't reflect the value they have to neither me nor you. It's not the avereage either, necesarily. The only thing we know is that the value of them to you is higher and to me is lower.
Not necessarily. You could have a transaction take place where the buyer and the seller both value what's being exchanged in exactly the same amount and then go through with the transaction anyway because they both find trades entertaining or have a cultural preference for doing business with each other or just both place zero value on transaction costs.
That isn't common but that doesn't mean it could never happen.
> The price of something and the value of something were never expected to be the same
While I agree with you (quite firmly: it’s a great starting point to put on the table to challenge orthodoxy in this space), and think you’re agreeing with the parent comment, it is a fundamental tenet of mainstream economics and the political arguments of neoliberal (aka current mainstream) policy that [price == (market averaged) value], or at the very least [price ~= value].
Another interesting line of argument is to explore things that are valuable that don’t typically get a price: for example household labour, or love and friendship (at least directly: I’m sure a Friedman acolyte would reduce all relationships to exchange and reframe gifts and acts of love as investments).
As an aside for the parent comment: thanks for sharing this, it’s one of the top category of comments/quotes I’ve seen on HN in being useful, insightful, and challenging of conventional understanding in a way that improves understanding and future prediction.
Note that in orthodox microeconomic theory, price is equal to the marginal value of the last exchanged unit. To use the above example of food:
> What's the value of food? If you have none you die, so the value is quit of high, but the price is much lower than that because there are many competing suppliers.
The first calories of the day, the ones that prevent you from dying, have a very high subjective value - but you pay them at the value of the 3000th calorie of the day, the extra drop of ketchup on your fries, which has a very little value.
And thus of course average value x volume is very different from (marginal value of last unit) x volume.
Mainstream economists believe that value >= price. This is where economic surplus comes from. This is why trade is not zero sum, and it's why trade causes societies to get wealthier. Friendship and love fit into this framework just fine, as the price is $0, but the value is greater than $0.
> While I agree with you (quite firmly: it’s a great starting point to put on the table to challenge orthodoxy in this space), and think you’re agreeing with the parent comment, it is a fundamental tenet of mainstream economics and the political arguments of neoliberal (aka current mainstream) policy that [price == (market averaged) value], or at the very least [price ~= value].
For mainstream economics, this is true in a very specific technical sense; all averages lose information, and the "market average" is a very particular form of average that doesn't behave the way most people think of an average behaving—particularly, it is not like a mean, the normal "average" that people think of, that is sensitive to changes in any individual values, it is somewhat like a median in that it is insensitive to changes in existing values that do not cross the "average"; e.g., if you take an existing market for a commodity with a given clearing price, and reduce, by any amount, the value of the commodity to any proper subset of sellers who would sell at the current market clearing price, the market clearing price does not change. The assessment of value across the market has decreased, but the output of the particular averaging function performed by the market has not.
It seems like Bookstaber argues not that it's liquidity demand over information change, but that it is both. The tariff announcements are actually a great example, because it was triggered by new information, and diversification still kind of worked (at least some government bonds gained value during the drop in other assets classes).
The main question, I suppose, is why correlations were so high after the tariff announcements:
- In some cases, the high correlations are probably due to the markets being directly affected by the announcements: both commodities and equity are affected, and they got more correlated, which makes sense.
- In some cases, the high correlations are probably due to liquidity demand rather than markets being directly affected by the announcements: we would not expect cryptocurrencies to be directly affected by US tariffs, but they ended up correlated with equity markets anyway. That's probably because people needed to sell off their cryptocurrency to cover equity losses.
Thus in this case, it's again probably a bit of both.
Sir this is just a casino. Stocks have nothing to do with the businesses right after they are issued. A business can opt to just never issue dividends (Hi Amazon). So the stock itself has 0 actual value. It does not generate cash. (Ok if the company goes belly up you will get a percentage of the carcass)
But we can all gamble on what it is worth!
So stockholders are like roulette pill holders. Everyone just bets on where the pill will fall. Few are luckier than others. Some smarter know whether the roullete is rigged and have better chances.
A company could decide to never pay a dividend, yes. But that doesn't mean the stock is worthless; you need to take the thought process further. Who ultimately controls a company? The shareholders. So, imagine a scenario where a company is profitable and seemingly valuable, but for some reason the share price is not increasing, so the shareholders are not seeing their wealth increase. In that scenario they would probably either pay a dividend or, more likely, take advantage of the profitability and low stock price to buy back stock, driving up its value.
Either way, the owners of a successful company are going to want to profit from it, which will make the shares valuable. Of course, investors know this, and so the share price tends to track current value of expected future earnings even without the company taking direct action to distribute profits.
the hypothesis maintains that
stock prices reflect all relevant
information about the stock
This is a common description of the EMH. But every time I read it, I think: Does information really directly impact the price of a stock? How?
What if it takes 12 months of hard thinking to draw the right conclusion from the information? Are there many investors who go to such lengths? Are they all thinking at the same speed? And if not, what does that tell us about the EMH?
Google released DeepDream in 2015. My feeling is that with enough thinking, one could have predicted where image generation is going in the next decade and that language generation would go a similar route. And that this will lead to a high demand in Nvidia's GPUs. But that thinking would not be instantly. It would take months or years.
Information that requires 12 months to figure out isn't information that's available now.
Say you want to know the 400 trillionth digit of pi. We have all the information needed right now to know how to compute it. But you don't know what the actual digit is yet. The information isn't available and won't be until you set your supercomputer on it for some number of months. Having the information necessary to derive other information isn't the same as having the derived information.
If there is some information about a future stock price that could theoretically be computed after months of work, that's still not information that currently exists, and therefore is not currently reflected in the price. If no investors go to the lengths to get that information, it'll continue to not affect the stock price. It's not violating EMH because it's not information that exists yet.
That definition would mean that smarter investors, who can think faster and further ahead, get information faster. And therefore have information now that others do not.
That seems to be directly the opposite of the common definition of the EMH, which emphasizes how the market reacts to new information. And not how it produces information. For example in TFA:
"the market rapidly responds to new information"
Wikipedia starts the "Theoretical background" with an example on how information becomes widely available to all investors, not how one fast smart thinker generates it:
Suppose that a piece of information about the value
of a stock (say, about a future merger) is widely
available to investors.
The smartest, fastest investors are the ones who make a profit by incorporating their information into the stock price in the EMH. The stock price can't move on its own. Under the EMH, someone has to be the first to trade stock based on information so that the stock price reflects it. When they say "the market rapidly responds to new information", that means investors with the new information are buying or selling accordingly. It's not opposite at all.
How the information gets produced is irrelevant to the EMH. Whether it's obvious or takes hard thinking, either way, once investors obtain the information, they will trade based on it, and that will move the stock price.
> What if it takes 12 months of hard thinking to draw the right conclusion from the information?
I think the idea behind EMH is that this probability is priced in, at any point in time. It just so happens that longer term probabilities are discounted as more volatile, thus impacting less the present price.
> What if it takes 12 months of hard thinking to draw the right conclusion from the information? Are there many investors who go to such lengths?
It's not required to be all of them. Suppose that it indeed isn't, but the ones who do that work for investment funds who control significant pools of money.
Now the investors in two or three of those places do the research and conclude that some company is about to start doing well and their share price is currently $50 but is about to be $150. So they start buying it, and keep buying it until it gets up near $150. Which happens pretty quickly because they control enough money to use up all of the short-term liquidity at the lower prices and the majority of the shares are held by people who aren't even paying attention and therefore don't try to sell when the price starts going up. Once the price gets to that point they don't buy any more because it's no longer selling at a discount.
Then the company actually starts doing well to the point that everyone can see it but the price hardly moves because it was already priced in.
That would mean that the p/e-ratio of a company would rise sharply long before the profits set in. And that rise would be called "mysterious" by the general public. And then only when the profits set in, the p/e would come down.
> That would mean that the p/e-ratio of a company would rise sharply long before the profits set in. And that rise would be called "mysterious" by the general public. And then only when the profits set in, the p/e would come down.
You have to look at the volumes involved: if there are tens of millions of shares of a particular stock moved everyday, a single event that involves 100,000 shares is going to be lost in the noise.
There are always people who think they know better (if they didn't think so they wouldn't be trading), and they may make crazy-appearing trades. Lots of the people in The Big Short were viewed as 'lunatics' ("You're betting against the housing market?") that turned out to be right. But also remember that there are people who think the world is flat.
> The price roughly rose along the earnings. Even though the foundations for generative AI became clear in 2015.
It's also why you hear the talking heads on television say things like "…this has already been priced in.".
You're not likely to see that in huge companies because everybody is already paying attention to them and it's harder to know something someone else doesn't about the thing everybody already knows everything about. Also, then it's more likely to happen on a scale of 10 days than 10 years.
Where that really happens is with startups and younger companies. Some company is currently making negative dollars but a few people have figured out that they're likely to be big so their share price is up before their earnings are.
And suppose you somehow actually knew what every major company's earnings would look like in every year from 2015 to now. Do you invest in Nvidia in 2015? Or do you invest in Netflix in 2015 and Tesla in 2019 and so on and not bother with Nvidia until just before the hockey stick?
The landmark paper, "Attention is all you need", that triggered the breakthrough that led to current transformer architecture LLMs, only came out in 2017. Without that breakthrough, they wouldn't exist. And even then, the early models produced gibberish. Better gibberish than older Markov chain text generators, but asking GPT-2 "What is three plus five?" would give some nonsense, non-sequitur answer, that might start with a (incorrect) number if you were lucky. At the time, everyone was wondering if scaling up the model size would improve intelligence or hit a wall. ChatGPT didn't release until 2022.
And you'd need to know back in 2015 that Nvidia specifically would be the big winner from AI. They don't even manufacture their own chips. Intel also designs chips and GPUs, but if you bet on them in 2015, you'd have lost money between then and 2025.
In systems thinking there’s the concept of “stocks” or “buffers”. Meaning that change of inputs into the systems first affect stocks/buffers before the outputs.
you're wrong about the mechanism - it's not that the thinking is the cause of the efficiency. It's the large number of participants all doing their own brand of thinking, and that the _average_ of all of those approaches the "correct" price. It requires the large number of participants because for such an average to approach "correct", errors within each participant's guesses cancel each other out.
And the immediacy comes from the large amount and speed of the transactions. It does not require that these participants sus out the correct value from information - they could've actually just guessed.
> What if it takes 12 months of hard thinking to draw the right conclusion from the information? Are there many investors who go to such lengths? Are they all thinking at the same speed? And if not, what does that tell us about the EMH?
To paraphrase William Gibson: the information may be available, but it is not evenly distributed.
It's why (e.g.) hedge funds use satellites to get information on company activities:
It's takes resources (time, money, etc) to gain an advantage, and it's only do it because they think some extra bits of information will allow them to know more than The Market in general / their counterparties to get a better conditions on a trade or options.
Why do you think insider trading became illegal: some folks have that information before others simply because of their job/position. There was a case of someone knowing something early, because information can only travel as fast of the speed of light, which some "beat":
> Last Wednesday, the Federal Reserve announced it would not be tapering its bond buying program at 2 p.m. ET. The news takes seven milliseconds — about the speed of light — to reach Chicago. But before the seven milliseconds was up, a few huge orders based on the Fed's decision were placed on Chicago exchanges.
EMH is saying people that if people think they can make money, they will spend the resources to get an information edge to accurate price what a commodity is 'worth', either higher or lower. If you better know what it 'should' be, then you can devise a trading strategy (buy/sell/short/long) to get one over your counterparty.
> if a sufficiently large majority of investors believe the hypothesis, they naturally would assume that new information about a stock would very quickly be reflected in its price. They would conclude that since relevant news almost immediately moves the price up or down, and since new developments can’t be predicted, neither can price increases or decreases
This is an oversimplification of how professional investing works.
The vast majority of the dollar value of markets isn’t governed by immediate profit seeking behaviour - it’s people trying to manage money in the context of a real business. Pension fund money is the largest “pot” in the markets at any one time.
Pensions funds aren’t incentivised to maximise returns in any particular quarter/year. Instead, they’re looking to manage risk and ensure consistent returns in the very long term.
Therefore, the “value” they place on various assets is different to what a trend fund or retail investor is thinking about. The price at which they would buy/sell is different.
The market value might “reflect” that information but it could easily create a situation in which short-term, strictly returns-motivated investors might value an asset much more than pension funds or vice versa. That creates opportunity for both to do a non-zero-sum trade and both “make money”.
I’ve seen it elsewhere in this thread but it’s simply not the case that the “markets are a casino”. The vast dollar value of the market is about sharing risk and providing liquidity.
The global bond market are at least 1.5 times the size of the equities market(s).
yes some markets are basically a casino but they’re tiny in comparison.
> The vast dollar value of the market is about sharing risk and providing liquidity.
This, very well summarized.
I would nuance (but not disagree with) your comments on pension funds though. The thing is PF do not invest themselves, they usually are, or delegate to, funds of funds, which in turn decide on allocation based on the desired risk profile. It could very well happen that the total allocation is the sum of a multitude of individually short term investments, as long as these are diversified enough. I would concede that in practice that is not really feasible though.
These risks profiles are numerous, diverse, and ultimately idiosyncratic. People often forget or don't know about all these risk constraints, because they work in a fund that is bound to a specific risk mandate.
For instance, depending on how your investment vehicule is structured (the regulatory enveloppe through which you sell your fund, which ultimately determines to who you can sell, how you can advertise, how profits are taxed, etc), you can have liquidity constraints (e.g. clients should be able to redempt daily, weekly, ...) risk parity constraints (e.g. per asset class vol budgets, to be respected daily, weekly, etc), exposure budgets (e.g. country, sector, beta, ...), counterparty risk (e.g. minimum number of managers to allocate to, or clearing houses, or custodians), idiosyncratic risks (e.g. an insurance company will need to be neutral against natural disasters, healthcare exposure, etc), ESG, etc
The efficient market hypothesis is a useful framework to understand complicated dynamic markets, but like almost all economic theories it isn't like a law of physics that explains reality 100%, but is a partial abstraction that explains key patterns of human behavior and information flow within markets.
You can think of it like a form of compression: it condenses an incredibly complex, chaotic system into something we can reason about. That simplification makes it powerful and insightful, but it also means that a lot of nuance and unpredictability are lost in the process. In contrast, a physical law can be calculated precisely and consistently, while market behavior is always shaped by human psychology, uncertainty, and imperfect information.
This seems to be a case of a feedback loop creating emergent behavior.
Let's say almost everyone believed in the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH). Then, trading would decrease significantly, since most people would think that stocks are already fairly priced. That means the few people who trade would move the market significantly, based on whatever idiosyncratic value-theories they had.
But then the EMH believers would see wild moves in the market and stop believing in EMH. They would start trading more to gain profits.
And as more traders participated, the market would behave more and more like the EMH were true. Eventually, the market would stabilize. Prices wouldn't swing so much. This would increase the number of EMH believers.
It would be interesting to survey belief in EMH among traders. If my model is correct, the percentage of EMH believers should be roughly constant, or at least oscillate around some optimum value.
Sounds a bit like the Adaptive Markets Hypothesis. In it there’s constant “evolution” between different trading strategies that become more or less efficient over time.
So here, Phase 1 would be a market dominated by EMH believers who passively invest. In phase 2, speculative “noisy” traders start to exploit this landscape to profit. In phase 3 there’s a crisis or period of high volatility. The old complacent EMH strategies suffer losses and become extinct. Then no doubt in phase 4 the market moves to some new equilibrium with new strategies dominant!
So in this AMH theory what you describe is a natural process of evolution.
> since most people would think that stocks are already fairly priced
Like the classic economist joke where they ignore a $100 bill on the ground: "It can't be real. If it were, somebody else would have already picked it up."
What you seem to be missing is that people don't solely derive value estimates based on the opinions of others. There are business fundamentals which can lead to one or more value estimates under different assumptions. If you don't do your own calculations, you may still read calculations from other people and reach a conclusion as to whether the true value of the stock is higher or lower than the market price.
EMH is about the tendency of the market to be efficient over time. It is purely of academic interest to dream up hypothetical scenarios where everyone is equally rational and informed, etc. There are degrees of efficiency and information, and it's useful to talk about this to try to understand how real markets work and can be made to work better.
The EMH is a description of how the market behaves when a sufficiently large number of independent actors are looking for alpha. It is not a prescription of how the market should behave.
The conclusion is that with a sufficiently large number of actors in the market all seeking profits by trying to find misevaluation of stock prices, the excess profits of any individual actor will (assuming they all have access to the same information) converge to zero.
Its less a paradox and more a matter of game theory. Every investment firm which gives up trying to look for alpha (believing it is fruitless) means the remaining firms have more opportunities to find stocks with available information not reflected in the price. There's no paradox here: each individual actor is incentivized to participate in order to not miss out on that potential for excess profits, and the net effect is the EMH.
Yeah, I think the "paradox" is usually a problem for pundits and academics and not practitioners. Lots of people have experience finding and correcting market inefficiencies, usually getting paid for it.
Information characterizing a company’s value isn’t the same thing as information indicating a company’s value. There can be a lot of analysis and model building in between. And different models can behave very differently, even if their prediction strength is similar.
Information publicly available doesn’t mean anyone can process it all. Every actor is operating off a different subset of information.
Lots of intentionally low information investors (inhabitants of indexed funds) demand stock or supply stock, pushing prices in directions unrelated to value changes, due to index list changes and rebalancing events.
Investors, of all magnitudes of wealth, have unending personal or private idiosyncratic reasons for the timing of many investments or sales, besides individual asset return optimization.
The value of a stock rises and falls as its absolute expected return rises and falls relative to the changing returns of the rest of the entire market of investment vehicles. Everything impacts everything.
All these shifts happen over varying time frames.
Almost all relevant market facts are time varying, often with turbulence and ambiguity.
The fast moving investors most influential in setting prices, must model the whole market’s 2nd order and even 3rd order reactions (by similar actors) due to feedback effects and dynamics.
Sudden market wide changes trigger waves of low analysis buying and selling. Compounded by the higher order risk this creates to leverage, annuity responsibikities, hedging, and many other amplifiers of behavior.
The efficient market hypothesis is an interesting and enlightening thought experiment. A reduced dimension toy/sim market.
Not a credible model.
Not even if every single participant was frantically and relentlessly re-valuing and re-balancing at the margins to a firehose of comprehensive market information.
I think what is unquestionable is that statistically, given available information, it is hard to make money against other market participants.
It is a form of informational efficiency, but it does not necessarily follow that prices are even statistically correct. The market can be irrational for longer than you can remain solvent.
My practical interpretation of the EMH is more that easily accessible, public information is already priced in. But non-obvious insights may not be simply because the volume of people trading on that information will be smaller.
Does the EMH state that prices will reflect on the price of a stock instantly? If not, I don’t think there’s a paradox. EMH would just mean it will eventually converge? I guess that makes it pretty toothless in practice then.
I feel like the stock market is pretty divorced from fundamentals at this point i.e. speculation makes it more like a Keynesian beauty contest (picking stocks you think other people will think are valuable).
> I feel like the stock market is pretty divorced from fundamentals at this point i.e. speculation makes it more like a Keynesian beauty contest (picking stocks you think other people will think are valuable).
Some institutional designs are more prone to Keynesian beauty contests than others.
It's instructive to compare "Crowdfunding" which took off with Kickstarter ~15 years ago, with "Equity Crowdfunding", which gets tried again and again, and has not a single success story to its name.
Kickstarter was made to fund artistic ventures, and for the first years, they were strict about only allowing that on their site. The idea was to reduce risk for e.g. people trying to bring their favorite band to the area for a concert.
On old Kickstarter, you only pledged to a project if YOU want the product/outcome for its own sake.
However, in "equity crowdfunding", where backers are tempted with a share in the profits of a venture, you should, if you are smart, try to ignore what YOU want. Your own wants are a source of error here: as a fan of the band, you're likely to overestimate its appeal. You should play the Keynesian beauty contest and try to guess what others want.
Kickstarter understood the difference very well. In the early years, they banned such things as "reseller's tiers". Some people would support e.g. a boardgame with pledging for five copies of the game, betting on its success and hoping to resell four of them. That brings the KBC factor in again, and Kickstarter thought that it would eventually lead to the site being flooded with the things everyone thought everyone else wanted, rather than the things they actually wanted.
There's a whole scam industry dedicated to exploiting the gap between what you want and what for its own sake and what you want because you think others want it: MLMs. MLM victims get tricked into a loop where they on one hand convince themselves that the product is great because they hope to sell it, and on the other convince themselves that the product will sell because it's great.
This is the truth. What drives the price up or down is speculation about whether the price will go up or down. There is only a very loose connection with actual company performance.
The EMH is obviously bs, as anyone with an ounce of common sense can observe from today’s market. To appeal to authority, buffet and monger and graham point out how insane Mr Market is, and they’ve done pretty well by exploiting its inefficiency.
Market prices are derived from supply and demand. A heavy determinant of demand is income equality. Another is interest rates. These are nothing to do with, in general, a particular stock.
It’s so obviously false to anyone trading or even watching stocks that serious discussion by academics just adds weight to the accusation that they don’t know what they’re talking about. We need a new, more serious, science of economics.
> The Grossman-Stiglitz Paradox is a paradox introduced by Sanford J. Grossman and Joseph Stiglitz in a joint publication in American Economic Review in 1980[1] that argues perfectly informationally efficient markets are an impossibility since, if prices perfectly reflected available information, there is no profit to gathering information, in which case there would be little reason to trade and markets would eventually collapse.[2]
So the more efficient markets are, the hard it will be to find "alpha" (returns), and so more people will stop trying. But as more people stop trying, markets will become more inefficient, in which case people can find alpha again, which encourages more participants.
Turnips and Carrots could be priced equally per tonne, and still be worth trading because although you might think all root vegetables are substitutable, it turns out you can't make carrot soup with Turnips.
It's always worth remembering trade involves use values as well. We don't only trade for asymmetric profit, and there are things like hedging which include a yield where both can acknowledge future risk, and price accordingly.
I'm probably ignorant of some magic economist reason why the words are fluid and don't mean what I think they mean: this always seems to be the case talking economics from the stuffed armchair.
Another take on this is that we can agree to facts and disagree to consequences. Same information, different conclusions.
I forget where I first heard it, but there's a joke about two economists walking down the street. One of them notices a $20 bill on the ground and points it out out, saying "Look, it's $20 just lying there on the sidewalk!" The other shakes his head and says "No, that can't be true; if it were, someone else would have picked it up already"
those insiders could be choosing an action that affects the markets, or thru inaction, affect the markets.
The current insider trading rules only prohibit actions, and does not prevent inaction.
As an example, you could imagine that an insider were going to sell their portfolio of company issued shares, but because of insider info they have about a current project that would give rise to a price hike, they may choose to sell _later_ (or not to sell at all). This means the liquidity of the market is now less, and thus, raises the price vs the counterfactual world where said insider _did_ sell. All without revealing any information about the actual insider project.
but doesnt the central limit theorem require each event to be i.i.d. ?
I dont think the efficient market is a result of the central limit theorem, since each transaction affecting the market is not independent of each other.
Anyone who has lived through a market correction (the tariff announcements in early April this year being a recent example, though there have been far worse) should be able to see that market prices do not always accurately reflect even the consensus view of value (which itself can be wrong). As people are forced to de-lever, everything goes down at once, often by very similar amounts, even though it cannot be possible that everything suddenly lost the same amount of value simultaneously.
To quote Richard Bookstaber, "The principal reason for intraday price movement is the demand for liquidity... the role of the market is to provide immediacy for liquidity demanders. ...market crises... are the times when liquidity and immediacy matter most. ...the defining characteristic is that time is more important than price. ...diversification strategies fail. Assets that are uncorrelated suddenly become highly correlated, and all positions go down together. The reason for the lack of diversification is that in a high-energy market, all assets in fact are the same.... What matters is who holds the assets." (from A Framework for Understanding Market Crises, 1999)
Was the market drop an accurate reflection of the value that would have been destroyed by those tariffs, discounted by the probability that they would have been enacted as drafted? Nobody knew then, and I maintain that nobody even knows now. That was not the calculation that was being made.
> As people are forced to de-lever, everything goes down at once, often by very similar amounts, even though it cannot be possible that everything suddenly lost the same amount of value simultaneously.
The price of something and the value of something were never expected to be the same. What's the value of food? If you have none you die, so the value is quite high, but the price is much lower than that because there are many competing suppliers.
And the price of a large class like investment securities can easily change all at once if there is a large shift in supply or demand.
Put another way: price is determined by need and supply (aka, demand curve meets supply curve).
I would pay anything for air if I needed it, but I will gladly sell air in my yard for $1/m^3 because that air is worthless to me.
Is air priceless or worthless?
That is why price != value as most people think of it.
Not disagreeing with you, but isn't that already obvious from the fact that economic activity happens in the first place?
If you buy 5 apples from me for $5 then two things must be true: 1. The value that those 5 apples have to you exceeds the value that $5 have to you, at least at this very moment. Otherwise you would hang on to your $5 instead. 2. The value that those 5 apples have to me is less than $5 have to me, otherwise I would hang on to the apples.
The price of those 5 apples at this moment may be $5 but that doesn't reflect the value they have to neither me nor you. It's not the avereage either, necesarily. The only thing we know is that the value of them to you is higher and to me is lower.
Not necessarily. You could have a transaction take place where the buyer and the seller both value what's being exchanged in exactly the same amount and then go through with the transaction anyway because they both find trades entertaining or have a cultural preference for doing business with each other or just both place zero value on transaction costs.
That isn't common but that doesn't mean it could never happen.
> The price of something and the value of something were never expected to be the same
While I agree with you (quite firmly: it’s a great starting point to put on the table to challenge orthodoxy in this space), and think you’re agreeing with the parent comment, it is a fundamental tenet of mainstream economics and the political arguments of neoliberal (aka current mainstream) policy that [price == (market averaged) value], or at the very least [price ~= value].
Another interesting line of argument is to explore things that are valuable that don’t typically get a price: for example household labour, or love and friendship (at least directly: I’m sure a Friedman acolyte would reduce all relationships to exchange and reframe gifts and acts of love as investments).
As an aside for the parent comment: thanks for sharing this, it’s one of the top category of comments/quotes I’ve seen on HN in being useful, insightful, and challenging of conventional understanding in a way that improves understanding and future prediction.
Note that in orthodox microeconomic theory, price is equal to the marginal value of the last exchanged unit. To use the above example of food:
> What's the value of food? If you have none you die, so the value is quit of high, but the price is much lower than that because there are many competing suppliers.
The first calories of the day, the ones that prevent you from dying, have a very high subjective value - but you pay them at the value of the 3000th calorie of the day, the extra drop of ketchup on your fries, which has a very little value.
And thus of course average value x volume is very different from (marginal value of last unit) x volume.
Mainstream economists believe that value >= price. This is where economic surplus comes from. This is why trade is not zero sum, and it's why trade causes societies to get wealthier. Friendship and love fit into this framework just fine, as the price is $0, but the value is greater than $0.
> While I agree with you (quite firmly: it’s a great starting point to put on the table to challenge orthodoxy in this space), and think you’re agreeing with the parent comment, it is a fundamental tenet of mainstream economics and the political arguments of neoliberal (aka current mainstream) policy that [price == (market averaged) value], or at the very least [price ~= value].
For mainstream economics, this is true in a very specific technical sense; all averages lose information, and the "market average" is a very particular form of average that doesn't behave the way most people think of an average behaving—particularly, it is not like a mean, the normal "average" that people think of, that is sensitive to changes in any individual values, it is somewhat like a median in that it is insensitive to changes in existing values that do not cross the "average"; e.g., if you take an existing market for a commodity with a given clearing price, and reduce, by any amount, the value of the commodity to any proper subset of sellers who would sell at the current market clearing price, the market clearing price does not change. The assessment of value across the market has decreased, but the output of the particular averaging function performed by the market has not.
It seems like Bookstaber argues not that it's liquidity demand over information change, but that it is both. The tariff announcements are actually a great example, because it was triggered by new information, and diversification still kind of worked (at least some government bonds gained value during the drop in other assets classes).
The main question, I suppose, is why correlations were so high after the tariff announcements:
- In some cases, the high correlations are probably due to the markets being directly affected by the announcements: both commodities and equity are affected, and they got more correlated, which makes sense.
- In some cases, the high correlations are probably due to liquidity demand rather than markets being directly affected by the announcements: we would not expect cryptocurrencies to be directly affected by US tariffs, but they ended up correlated with equity markets anyway. That's probably because people needed to sell off their cryptocurrency to cover equity losses.
Thus in this case, it's again probably a bit of both.
Great paper. Thanks for referencing.
Sir this is just a casino. Stocks have nothing to do with the businesses right after they are issued. A business can opt to just never issue dividends (Hi Amazon). So the stock itself has 0 actual value. It does not generate cash. (Ok if the company goes belly up you will get a percentage of the carcass)
But we can all gamble on what it is worth!
So stockholders are like roulette pill holders. Everyone just bets on where the pill will fall. Few are luckier than others. Some smarter know whether the roullete is rigged and have better chances.
A company could decide to never pay a dividend, yes. But that doesn't mean the stock is worthless; you need to take the thought process further. Who ultimately controls a company? The shareholders. So, imagine a scenario where a company is profitable and seemingly valuable, but for some reason the share price is not increasing, so the shareholders are not seeing their wealth increase. In that scenario they would probably either pay a dividend or, more likely, take advantage of the profitability and low stock price to buy back stock, driving up its value.
Either way, the owners of a successful company are going to want to profit from it, which will make the shares valuable. Of course, investors know this, and so the share price tends to track current value of expected future earnings even without the company taking direct action to distribute profits.
What if it takes 12 months of hard thinking to draw the right conclusion from the information? Are there many investors who go to such lengths? Are they all thinking at the same speed? And if not, what does that tell us about the EMH?
Google released DeepDream in 2015. My feeling is that with enough thinking, one could have predicted where image generation is going in the next decade and that language generation would go a similar route. And that this will lead to a high demand in Nvidia's GPUs. But that thinking would not be instantly. It would take months or years.
Information that requires 12 months to figure out isn't information that's available now.
Say you want to know the 400 trillionth digit of pi. We have all the information needed right now to know how to compute it. But you don't know what the actual digit is yet. The information isn't available and won't be until you set your supercomputer on it for some number of months. Having the information necessary to derive other information isn't the same as having the derived information.
If there is some information about a future stock price that could theoretically be computed after months of work, that's still not information that currently exists, and therefore is not currently reflected in the price. If no investors go to the lengths to get that information, it'll continue to not affect the stock price. It's not violating EMH because it's not information that exists yet.
That definition would mean that smarter investors, who can think faster and further ahead, get information faster. And therefore have information now that others do not.
That seems to be directly the opposite of the common definition of the EMH, which emphasizes how the market reacts to new information. And not how it produces information. For example in TFA:
"the market rapidly responds to new information"
Wikipedia starts the "Theoretical background" with an example on how information becomes widely available to all investors, not how one fast smart thinker generates it:
https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Efficient-market_hypothesisThe smartest, fastest investors are the ones who make a profit by incorporating their information into the stock price in the EMH. The stock price can't move on its own. Under the EMH, someone has to be the first to trade stock based on information so that the stock price reflects it. When they say "the market rapidly responds to new information", that means investors with the new information are buying or selling accordingly. It's not opposite at all.
How the information gets produced is irrelevant to the EMH. Whether it's obvious or takes hard thinking, either way, once investors obtain the information, they will trade based on it, and that will move the stock price.
> What if it takes 12 months of hard thinking to draw the right conclusion from the information?
I think the idea behind EMH is that this probability is priced in, at any point in time. It just so happens that longer term probabilities are discounted as more volatile, thus impacting less the present price.
> What if it takes 12 months of hard thinking to draw the right conclusion from the information? Are there many investors who go to such lengths?
It's not required to be all of them. Suppose that it indeed isn't, but the ones who do that work for investment funds who control significant pools of money.
Now the investors in two or three of those places do the research and conclude that some company is about to start doing well and their share price is currently $50 but is about to be $150. So they start buying it, and keep buying it until it gets up near $150. Which happens pretty quickly because they control enough money to use up all of the short-term liquidity at the lower prices and the majority of the shares are held by people who aren't even paying attention and therefore don't try to sell when the price starts going up. Once the price gets to that point they don't buy any more because it's no longer selling at a discount.
Then the company actually starts doing well to the point that everyone can see it but the price hardly moves because it was already priced in.
But do we see that happen?
That would mean that the p/e-ratio of a company would rise sharply long before the profits set in. And that rise would be called "mysterious" by the general public. And then only when the profits set in, the p/e would come down.
I can't see that in Nvidia for example:
https://www.macrotrends.net/stocks/charts/NVDA/nvidia/pe-rat...
The price roughly rose along the earnings. Even though the foundations for generative AI became clear in 2015.
> That would mean that the p/e-ratio of a company would rise sharply long before the profits set in. And that rise would be called "mysterious" by the general public. And then only when the profits set in, the p/e would come down.
You have to look at the volumes involved: if there are tens of millions of shares of a particular stock moved everyday, a single event that involves 100,000 shares is going to be lost in the noise.
There are always people who think they know better (if they didn't think so they wouldn't be trading), and they may make crazy-appearing trades. Lots of the people in The Big Short were viewed as 'lunatics' ("You're betting against the housing market?") that turned out to be right. But also remember that there are people who think the world is flat.
> The price roughly rose along the earnings. Even though the foundations for generative AI became clear in 2015.
It's also why you hear the talking heads on television say things like "…this has already been priced in.".
You're not likely to see that in huge companies because everybody is already paying attention to them and it's harder to know something someone else doesn't about the thing everybody already knows everything about. Also, then it's more likely to happen on a scale of 10 days than 10 years.
Where that really happens is with startups and younger companies. Some company is currently making negative dollars but a few people have figured out that they're likely to be big so their share price is up before their earnings are.
And suppose you somehow actually knew what every major company's earnings would look like in every year from 2015 to now. Do you invest in Nvidia in 2015? Or do you invest in Netflix in 2015 and Tesla in 2019 and so on and not bother with Nvidia until just before the hockey stick?
The landmark paper, "Attention is all you need", that triggered the breakthrough that led to current transformer architecture LLMs, only came out in 2017. Without that breakthrough, they wouldn't exist. And even then, the early models produced gibberish. Better gibberish than older Markov chain text generators, but asking GPT-2 "What is three plus five?" would give some nonsense, non-sequitur answer, that might start with a (incorrect) number if you were lucky. At the time, everyone was wondering if scaling up the model size would improve intelligence or hit a wall. ChatGPT didn't release until 2022.
And you'd need to know back in 2015 that Nvidia specifically would be the big winner from AI. They don't even manufacture their own chips. Intel also designs chips and GPUs, but if you bet on them in 2015, you'd have lost money between then and 2025.
In systems thinking there’s the concept of “stocks” or “buffers”. Meaning that change of inputs into the systems first affect stocks/buffers before the outputs.
you're wrong about the mechanism - it's not that the thinking is the cause of the efficiency. It's the large number of participants all doing their own brand of thinking, and that the _average_ of all of those approaches the "correct" price. It requires the large number of participants because for such an average to approach "correct", errors within each participant's guesses cancel each other out.
And the immediacy comes from the large amount and speed of the transactions. It does not require that these participants sus out the correct value from information - they could've actually just guessed.
> What if it takes 12 months of hard thinking to draw the right conclusion from the information? Are there many investors who go to such lengths? Are they all thinking at the same speed? And if not, what does that tell us about the EMH?
To paraphrase William Gibson: the information may be available, but it is not evenly distributed.
It's why (e.g.) hedge funds use satellites to get information on company activities:
* https://newsroom.haas.berkeley.edu/how-hedge-funds-use-satel...
* https://internationalbanker.com/brokerage/how-satellite-imag...
It's takes resources (time, money, etc) to gain an advantage, and it's only do it because they think some extra bits of information will allow them to know more than The Market in general / their counterparties to get a better conditions on a trade or options.
Why do you think insider trading became illegal: some folks have that information before others simply because of their job/position. There was a case of someone knowing something early, because information can only travel as fast of the speed of light, which some "beat":
> Last Wednesday, the Federal Reserve announced it would not be tapering its bond buying program at 2 p.m. ET. The news takes seven milliseconds — about the speed of light — to reach Chicago. But before the seven milliseconds was up, a few huge orders based on the Fed's decision were placed on Chicago exchanges.
* https://www.npr.org/sections/alltechconsidered/2013/09/24/22...
* https://www.motherjones.com/kevin-drum/2013/11/final-frontie...
EMH is saying people that if people think they can make money, they will spend the resources to get an information edge to accurate price what a commodity is 'worth', either higher or lower. If you better know what it 'should' be, then you can devise a trading strategy (buy/sell/short/long) to get one over your counterparty.
> if a sufficiently large majority of investors believe the hypothesis, they naturally would assume that new information about a stock would very quickly be reflected in its price. They would conclude that since relevant news almost immediately moves the price up or down, and since new developments can’t be predicted, neither can price increases or decreases
This is an oversimplification of how professional investing works.
The vast majority of the dollar value of markets isn’t governed by immediate profit seeking behaviour - it’s people trying to manage money in the context of a real business. Pension fund money is the largest “pot” in the markets at any one time.
Pensions funds aren’t incentivised to maximise returns in any particular quarter/year. Instead, they’re looking to manage risk and ensure consistent returns in the very long term.
Therefore, the “value” they place on various assets is different to what a trend fund or retail investor is thinking about. The price at which they would buy/sell is different.
The market value might “reflect” that information but it could easily create a situation in which short-term, strictly returns-motivated investors might value an asset much more than pension funds or vice versa. That creates opportunity for both to do a non-zero-sum trade and both “make money”.
I’ve seen it elsewhere in this thread but it’s simply not the case that the “markets are a casino”. The vast dollar value of the market is about sharing risk and providing liquidity.
The global bond market are at least 1.5 times the size of the equities market(s).
yes some markets are basically a casino but they’re tiny in comparison.
> The vast dollar value of the market is about sharing risk and providing liquidity.
This, very well summarized.
I would nuance (but not disagree with) your comments on pension funds though. The thing is PF do not invest themselves, they usually are, or delegate to, funds of funds, which in turn decide on allocation based on the desired risk profile. It could very well happen that the total allocation is the sum of a multitude of individually short term investments, as long as these are diversified enough. I would concede that in practice that is not really feasible though.
These risks profiles are numerous, diverse, and ultimately idiosyncratic. People often forget or don't know about all these risk constraints, because they work in a fund that is bound to a specific risk mandate.
For instance, depending on how your investment vehicule is structured (the regulatory enveloppe through which you sell your fund, which ultimately determines to who you can sell, how you can advertise, how profits are taxed, etc), you can have liquidity constraints (e.g. clients should be able to redempt daily, weekly, ...) risk parity constraints (e.g. per asset class vol budgets, to be respected daily, weekly, etc), exposure budgets (e.g. country, sector, beta, ...), counterparty risk (e.g. minimum number of managers to allocate to, or clearing houses, or custodians), idiosyncratic risks (e.g. an insurance company will need to be neutral against natural disasters, healthcare exposure, etc), ESG, etc
The efficient market hypothesis is a useful framework to understand complicated dynamic markets, but like almost all economic theories it isn't like a law of physics that explains reality 100%, but is a partial abstraction that explains key patterns of human behavior and information flow within markets.
You can think of it like a form of compression: it condenses an incredibly complex, chaotic system into something we can reason about. That simplification makes it powerful and insightful, but it also means that a lot of nuance and unpredictability are lost in the process. In contrast, a physical law can be calculated precisely and consistently, while market behavior is always shaped by human psychology, uncertainty, and imperfect information.
This seems to be a case of a feedback loop creating emergent behavior.
Let's say almost everyone believed in the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH). Then, trading would decrease significantly, since most people would think that stocks are already fairly priced. That means the few people who trade would move the market significantly, based on whatever idiosyncratic value-theories they had.
But then the EMH believers would see wild moves in the market and stop believing in EMH. They would start trading more to gain profits.
And as more traders participated, the market would behave more and more like the EMH were true. Eventually, the market would stabilize. Prices wouldn't swing so much. This would increase the number of EMH believers.
It would be interesting to survey belief in EMH among traders. If my model is correct, the percentage of EMH believers should be roughly constant, or at least oscillate around some optimum value.
Sounds a bit like the Adaptive Markets Hypothesis. In it there’s constant “evolution” between different trading strategies that become more or less efficient over time.
So here, Phase 1 would be a market dominated by EMH believers who passively invest. In phase 2, speculative “noisy” traders start to exploit this landscape to profit. In phase 3 there’s a crisis or period of high volatility. The old complacent EMH strategies suffer losses and become extinct. Then no doubt in phase 4 the market moves to some new equilibrium with new strategies dominant!
So in this AMH theory what you describe is a natural process of evolution.
> since most people would think that stocks are already fairly priced
Like the classic economist joke where they ignore a $100 bill on the ground: "It can't be real. If it were, somebody else would have already picked it up."
What you seem to be missing is that people don't solely derive value estimates based on the opinions of others. There are business fundamentals which can lead to one or more value estimates under different assumptions. If you don't do your own calculations, you may still read calculations from other people and reach a conclusion as to whether the true value of the stock is higher or lower than the market price.
EMH is about the tendency of the market to be efficient over time. It is purely of academic interest to dream up hypothetical scenarios where everyone is equally rational and informed, etc. There are degrees of efficiency and information, and it's useful to talk about this to try to understand how real markets work and can be made to work better.
The EMH is a description of how the market behaves when a sufficiently large number of independent actors are looking for alpha. It is not a prescription of how the market should behave.
The conclusion is that with a sufficiently large number of actors in the market all seeking profits by trying to find misevaluation of stock prices, the excess profits of any individual actor will (assuming they all have access to the same information) converge to zero.
Its less a paradox and more a matter of game theory. Every investment firm which gives up trying to look for alpha (believing it is fruitless) means the remaining firms have more opportunities to find stocks with available information not reflected in the price. There's no paradox here: each individual actor is incentivized to participate in order to not miss out on that potential for excess profits, and the net effect is the EMH.
Yeah, I think the "paradox" is usually a problem for pundits and academics and not practitioners. Lots of people have experience finding and correcting market inefficiencies, usually getting paid for it.
Information characterizing a company’s value isn’t the same thing as information indicating a company’s value. There can be a lot of analysis and model building in between. And different models can behave very differently, even if their prediction strength is similar.
Information publicly available doesn’t mean anyone can process it all. Every actor is operating off a different subset of information.
Lots of intentionally low information investors (inhabitants of indexed funds) demand stock or supply stock, pushing prices in directions unrelated to value changes, due to index list changes and rebalancing events.
Investors, of all magnitudes of wealth, have unending personal or private idiosyncratic reasons for the timing of many investments or sales, besides individual asset return optimization.
The value of a stock rises and falls as its absolute expected return rises and falls relative to the changing returns of the rest of the entire market of investment vehicles. Everything impacts everything.
All these shifts happen over varying time frames.
Almost all relevant market facts are time varying, often with turbulence and ambiguity.
The fast moving investors most influential in setting prices, must model the whole market’s 2nd order and even 3rd order reactions (by similar actors) due to feedback effects and dynamics.
Sudden market wide changes trigger waves of low analysis buying and selling. Compounded by the higher order risk this creates to leverage, annuity responsibikities, hedging, and many other amplifiers of behavior.
The efficient market hypothesis is an interesting and enlightening thought experiment. A reduced dimension toy/sim market.
Not a credible model.
Not even if every single participant was frantically and relentlessly re-valuing and re-balancing at the margins to a firehose of comprehensive market information.
I think what is unquestionable is that statistically, given available information, it is hard to make money against other market participants.
It is a form of informational efficiency, but it does not necessarily follow that prices are even statistically correct. The market can be irrational for longer than you can remain solvent.
My practical interpretation of the EMH is more that easily accessible, public information is already priced in. But non-obvious insights may not be simply because the volume of people trading on that information will be smaller.
Does the EMH state that prices will reflect on the price of a stock instantly? If not, I don’t think there’s a paradox. EMH would just mean it will eventually converge? I guess that makes it pretty toothless in practice then.
I feel like the stock market is pretty divorced from fundamentals at this point i.e. speculation makes it more like a Keynesian beauty contest (picking stocks you think other people will think are valuable).
https://en.m.wikipedia.org/wiki/Keynesian_beauty_contest
> I feel like the stock market is pretty divorced from fundamentals at this point i.e. speculation makes it more like a Keynesian beauty contest (picking stocks you think other people will think are valuable).
Momentum investing is a thing:
* https://www.investopedia.com/terms/m/momentum.asp
* https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Momentum_investing
A number of people make / made money when The Market became "divorced from fundamentals": see The Big Short.
* https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/The_Big_Short_(film)
Just remember: "The market remain irrational longer than you can remain solvent." — Keynes, https://www.goodreads.com/quotes/603621
Some institutional designs are more prone to Keynesian beauty contests than others.
It's instructive to compare "Crowdfunding" which took off with Kickstarter ~15 years ago, with "Equity Crowdfunding", which gets tried again and again, and has not a single success story to its name.
Kickstarter was made to fund artistic ventures, and for the first years, they were strict about only allowing that on their site. The idea was to reduce risk for e.g. people trying to bring their favorite band to the area for a concert.
On old Kickstarter, you only pledged to a project if YOU want the product/outcome for its own sake.
However, in "equity crowdfunding", where backers are tempted with a share in the profits of a venture, you should, if you are smart, try to ignore what YOU want. Your own wants are a source of error here: as a fan of the band, you're likely to overestimate its appeal. You should play the Keynesian beauty contest and try to guess what others want.
Kickstarter understood the difference very well. In the early years, they banned such things as "reseller's tiers". Some people would support e.g. a boardgame with pledging for five copies of the game, betting on its success and hoping to resell four of them. That brings the KBC factor in again, and Kickstarter thought that it would eventually lead to the site being flooded with the things everyone thought everyone else wanted, rather than the things they actually wanted.
There's a whole scam industry dedicated to exploiting the gap between what you want and what for its own sake and what you want because you think others want it: MLMs. MLM victims get tricked into a loop where they on one hand convince themselves that the product is great because they hope to sell it, and on the other convince themselves that the product will sell because it's great.
This is the truth. What drives the price up or down is speculation about whether the price will go up or down. There is only a very loose connection with actual company performance.
The EMH is obviously bs, as anyone with an ounce of common sense can observe from today’s market. To appeal to authority, buffet and monger and graham point out how insane Mr Market is, and they’ve done pretty well by exploiting its inefficiency.
Market prices are derived from supply and demand. A heavy determinant of demand is income equality. Another is interest rates. These are nothing to do with, in general, a particular stock.
It’s so obviously false to anyone trading or even watching stocks that serious discussion by academics just adds weight to the accusation that they don’t know what they’re talking about. We need a new, more serious, science of economics.
All models are flawed; some are useful. I would argue the EMH is an imperfect but useful model of market behaviour.
You make a good point and I’m open to changing my mind.
How do you think it’s useful? Can it be used to make predictions about the future, for example?
See also:
> The Grossman-Stiglitz Paradox is a paradox introduced by Sanford J. Grossman and Joseph Stiglitz in a joint publication in American Economic Review in 1980[1] that argues perfectly informationally efficient markets are an impossibility since, if prices perfectly reflected available information, there is no profit to gathering information, in which case there would be little reason to trade and markets would eventually collapse.[2]
* https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Grossman-Stiglitz_paradox
So the more efficient markets are, the hard it will be to find "alpha" (returns), and so more people will stop trying. But as more people stop trying, markets will become more inefficient, in which case people can find alpha again, which encourages more participants.
Turnips and Carrots could be priced equally per tonne, and still be worth trading because although you might think all root vegetables are substitutable, it turns out you can't make carrot soup with Turnips.
It's always worth remembering trade involves use values as well. We don't only trade for asymmetric profit, and there are things like hedging which include a yield where both can acknowledge future risk, and price accordingly.
I'm probably ignorant of some magic economist reason why the words are fluid and don't mean what I think they mean: this always seems to be the case talking economics from the stuffed armchair.
Another take on this is that we can agree to facts and disagree to consequences. Same information, different conclusions.
This plays directly into fisher Black's "Noise" http://www.e-m-h.org/Blac86.pdf
I forget where I first heard it, but there's a joke about two economists walking down the street. One of them notices a $20 bill on the ground and points it out out, saying "Look, it's $20 just lying there on the sidewalk!" The other shakes his head and says "No, that can't be true; if it were, someone else would have picked it up already"
This joke was in the article?
Reading the article would have been inefficient.
For this paradox to function, information would have to be static, unless I'm missing something.
Also wouldn’t all information have to be available to all participants? How does insider knowledge factor here (because it sure does in the market)
those insiders could be choosing an action that affects the markets, or thru inaction, affect the markets.
The current insider trading rules only prohibit actions, and does not prevent inaction.
As an example, you could imagine that an insider were going to sell their portfolio of company issued shares, but because of insider info they have about a current project that would give rise to a price hike, they may choose to sell _later_ (or not to sell at all). This means the liquidity of the market is now less, and thus, raises the price vs the counterfactual world where said insider _did_ sell. All without revealing any information about the actual insider project.
For a sufficiently large market, over time, one would expect the Central Limit Theorem to kick in and filter the noise.
The "Efficient Market" can be seen as an Eternal Steady State, neglecting all transient signals.
but doesnt the central limit theorem require each event to be i.i.d. ?
I dont think the efficient market is a result of the central limit theorem, since each transaction affecting the market is not independent of each other.
Nancy Palosi.
EMH is nonsense that is repeated routinely to scare people from trading the market.